Software Litigation Consulting

Andrew Schulman
Consulting Technical Expert & Attorney

NotebookLM-generated audio on my notes for “Patent Litigation” book

[Transcript of audio generated by NotebookLM from my notes for forthcoming book on Patent Litigation (see https://www.softwarelitigationconsulting.com/writing-patent-litigation-book-with-notebooklm/). My notes in bold italic like this. I’ll soon trying to introduce these into the audio with NotebookLM “Interactive mode”. I’ve highlighted with bold underlining a few key points that NotebookLM expressed better than did my notes.]

Welcome to the deep dive, where we plunge into a stack of your sources to extract the most important nuggets of knowledge and insight. Today, we’re navigating the uh surprisingly complex world of patent litigation. It’s a place where abstract ideas meet very concrete, sometimes staggering financial outcomes. Okay, let’s unpack this a bit. You might have heard about that Caltech patent case.

Oh, yeah. Big headlines on that one, right? A university gets awarded a cool billion dollars for a patent that well to a lot of folks it just looked like a graph or a diagram a billion dollars for one patent. How does that even begin to happen? [Actually, four patents were at issue in the case. I tried correcting the audio using NotebookLM’s audio “Interactive Mode,” but the two speakers got sidetracked.]

Well that’s exactly what we want to dig into in this deep dive. We’re going to peel back the layers on how patents really work especially you know when they end up in a high stakes courtroom and we’ll try to connect these um intricate legal battles back to that grand constitutional purpose right promoting the progress of science and useful arts. You’ve given us a stack of fascinating sources here and our mission is really to help you understand what’s truly at stake and frankly why it matters.

Absolutely. So, we’ll explore patents as this unique kind of property and then delve into how they’re enforced, how they’re challenged, and ultimately how they’re valued sometimes. Yeah. To that billion dollar tune. And all along we’ll be asking, is this immense complexity, this cost, is it really promoting innovation or is it like one of our sources kind of provocatively puts it, a Rube Goldberg way of getting to progress. [The “or” suggests a false dichotomy. My notes point to the patent system, including patent litigation, as a convoluted (but perhaps necessarily convoluted) way of “promoting progress of science and the useful arts,” as the US Constitution puts it.]

So, let’s start with maybe a foundational idea. Patents are often compared to land, you know, real property.

Not a common analogy. [Actually is a fairly common analogy, though one that some resist because of a misconception that real property suggests unrestricted power, whereas we know that use of one’s real estate comes with plenty of restrictions. The NotebookLM makes this point below, e.g. zoning.]

It sounds intuitive, but how does that comparison actually work for something you can’t touch, like an invention? You can’t exactly put a fence around an idea, can you? [While it’s true on the one hand that an invention is almost never identical with a tangle product on the market that may embody or practice the invention, on the other hand the invention covered by a patent is not some wholly immaterial abstraction either; see e.g.  “reduction to practice” — even so-called “constructive” reduction to practice (basically, the ability to write a patent application) requires ability to disclose how to make and use the invention, without undue experimentation.]

Well, it’s a useful analogy, even with its limits. Think of it less like owning the land itself, and more like having the right to exclude others. So, it’s your right to stop people from making, using, selling, or importing your invention. You can ask the government through the courts to help you deal with trespassers or as we call them in patent law infringers. But just like owning land is [not] an absolute you have zoning laws, eminent domain, things like that. Intellectual property also has built-in boundaries and limits. The whole point of the patent system in a way is to create those boundaries to make intangible ideas more well tangible legally. And here’s a really key point, something that surprises a lot of people. Patent infringement. It’s a civil matter. It’s not a crime.

Oh, okay. So, not like that. Exactly. You’re not stealing an idea in the criminal sense. And get this, you can actually infringe a patent without ever even seeing it, without copying anything. If you independently invent something and it happens to fall within the boundaries, the claims of someone else’s existing patent, boom, you’re an infringer.

Okay. So, if a patent sets these boundaries, these property lines, how do you actually figure out if someone’s crossed them? It can’t just be a gut feeling like, “Hey, that product looks kind of similar to mine, right?”

Oh, definitely not. It’s far more precise than that. Proving infringement isn’t about a general vibe or resemblance. It’s a really meticulous uh limitation by limitation analysis. You have to compare a very specific part of the patent, what we call the claims, directly to the accused product or process.

The claims. Okay.

Yeah. Think of the claims as the uh the real business end of the patent. They’re like the legal fences, totally distinct from the title or the abstract or even the drawings. [Well, not totally distinct. Other parts of the patent form necessary context (and sometimes even a “dictionary”) for the claims.]

The claims are the tools you use to test for infringement. And each claim is broken down into individual parts requirements. We call those limitations.

Limitations. Got it.

So, imagine uh let’s say a hypothetical patent claim for printer toner. It might list three key ingredients. Limitation one, a crystalline polyester resin, limitation two, a photopolymerization initiator, and limitation three, a thiol compound. Now, to literally infringe that claim, the competitor’s toner has to contain each and every one of those limitations. All three. So if it only has two like the resin and the initiator but not the [thiol compound], then nope no literal infringement of that specific claim. Now a big challenge here for the patent owner is they often don’t know exactly what’s inside the competitor’s product or process. [The “hypothetical” patent here is US S 8,951,704 which is discussed in part 2 of a 6-part series on patent litigation I wrote some time ago.]

Right. Trade secrets and all that.

Exactly. So that’s where things like reverse engineering come in and especially the discovery phase in a lawsuit. That’s how you get access to internal documents, maybe even source code to actually map against a patent’s claims. [Reverse engineering particularly important as part of “reasonable investigation” pre-litigation, before filing suit.]

Okay. But what if the words don’t match up perfectly? Say the patent claim talks about a widget, but the accused product calls it similar part a gizmo. Does that get them off the hook?

Ah, yeah, that’s a super common issue. The specific words used, the nomenclature in a patent claim, often won’t line up exactly with how a company describes its own product or components. But that doesn’t automatically mean there’s no literal infringement. If the underlying thing, the element, is functionally the same, the name doesn’t really matter. It’s substance over labels. And even if there isn’t that direct literal match for every single limitation, there’s a kind of fallback. It’s called the doctrine of equivalence. [This paragraph sounded on first listening like it was presenting a holistic view of equivalence, but the next paragraph clarifies it’s done element-by-element. It also sounded like a loose take on “functionally the same,” but the next paragraph reflects the function/way/result test.]

Okay, this basically says, okay, maybe it’s not identical, but if a feature in the product is really similar and does the same job in the same way to get the same result, it might still infringe. So maybe the claim says web browser, but the product uses some custom XML browser that does essentially the same thing in that context. That could be equivalent. But importantly, this Equivalence test is also applied limitation by limitation, not just comparing the whole thing overall.

And actually, before you even get to comparing the claim to the product, there’s this huge critical step called claim construction.

Yeah. Think of it like this. Before you argue about whether someone trespassed, you first have to agree on exactly where the property lines were drawn. That’s claim construction. Lawyers and judges spend a massive amount of time and money just interpreting the precise meaning of the words used in the patent claims. This happens before the infringement analysis. It clarifies what a term a limitation actually covers. And sometimes, yeah, this interpretation can effectively broaden the raw language of the claim a bit. [“This happens before the infringement analysis” is black-letter law, but in practice the parties will only fight over the meaning of a small subset of claim elements that, depending on the meaning, are contestably present or not-present in the accused product or asserted prior art.]

Okay? So, the patent owner files a lawsuit. They lay out their case for infringement using these detailed claim charts. They bring in experts, right?

But the defendant isn’t just sitting there. They have a really powerful counter move, right? Trying to prove the patent shouldn’t have been granted in the first place, that it’s invalid. Exactly. It’s a crucial defense which raises a pretty fundamental question. How can something the government officially granted like a patent just be declared invalid later on?

That’s an excellent question and you’re right. A patent issued by the patent office is presumed to be valid. That presumption carries real weight in court. However, and this is a big however, that presumption is rebuttable. The defendant can overcome it if they present clear and convincing evidence that the patent office made a mistake. And here’s where the Stakes get incredibly high for the patent owner. One of our sources calls it a use it and lose it situation.

Lose it. [The speaker should be asking “And lose it?”, because the normal phrase is “Use it or lose it,” and the point here is the possibility of “Use it and lose it,” because asserting a patent incentivizes the defendant to try to invalidate the patent.]

Yeah. If your patent gets invalidated in a lawsuit against one company, it’s almost certainly invalidated forever against everyone. Poof, gone. Which leads some people to argue, maybe only half jokingly, that the only truly safe patent is one that isn’t used in litigation. [“Almost certainly”? I’m not sure my notes said that. This may raise issues of RJ (res judicata), especially non-mutual RJ, and CE (collateral estoppel)?]

Wow. So, okay. How does a defendant actually do that? How do they invalidate a patent? It sounds like, I don’t know, some kind of intense legal archaeology. digging for dirt.

It really is. It’s like detective work. There are several main ways they attack validity. First, there’s anticipation. This basically means the invention wasn’t actually new. It was already known it was part of the prior art. To prove anticipation, the defendant has to find every single limitation of the patent claim described in one single earlier document or thing. A single piece of prior art. [Probably would be helpful for audio to note that patent examiner gets maybe 20 hours with the patent application, and applicant need only disclose known prior art, without a proactive duty to go looking for it, so prior art could have slipped by.]

And that prior art could be anything.

Almost anything. It could be another patent. Sure. But it could also be an old scientific paper, a PhD thesis, gathering dust in a library, a product manual, even a presentation given at some obscure conference years ago. Anywhere in the world, in any language, it can be incredibly obscure stuff. [This sounds unfair, but remember, a patent is only awarded for novel technology.]

The second big way is obviousness. This is a bit different. Even if you can’t find all the claim limitations in one single prior art reference, maybe combining two or three known things would have made the invention obvious to someone skilled in that particular technology area at the time the patent was filed. We call that hypothetical person the [PHOSITA]. The person having ordinary skill in the pertinent art

Yeah. So for obviousness you have to show not just that the pieces existed but that there was some reason or motivation for a [PHOSITA; transcript says “fauceta” :-)] to combine them in that way even if nobody actually did combine them back then.

Then there’s lack of enablement. This attacks the patent document itself. The descriptive part the specification has to teach someone skilled in the art how to actually make and use the invention with without needing, you know, excessive or undue experimentation.

So, the instructions have to be good enough.

Exactly. The patent has to deliver on its promise to teach the public.

And finally, there are other ways, too, like the on sale bar or public use bar. If the inventor themselves sold the invention or used it publicly more than a year before they filed for the patent, that can also kill the patent.

This whole thing sounds incredibly intricate, like that phrase from one of the sources, threading the needle. It feels like a very high stakes legal tightrope walk.

That threading the needle analogy is spot on. Patent drafting and then litigating it is this constant balancing act. You’re navigating between two dangers. On one side, you’ve got over breath. If you write your patent claims too short and broad, well, it makes it easier to catch infringers, right? More things fall inside your boundaries. [“Too short and too broad” is absolutely correct in infringement analysis, but perhaps should have been explained, given the tendency to view a longer patent claim as somehow meatier, whereas when looking for potential infringement, the opposite is correct. A shorter patent claim will be weaker (easier to invalidate) in comparison with the prior art.]

But it also makes your patent much more likely to be invalid because it’s easier for some piece of prior art to contain all those few limitations.

Okay. Easier to infringe. but easier to kill.

Exactly. Then on the other side, you have over narrowness. If you make your claim super long and specific, adding lots of limitations, it makes your patent really strong against validity attacks, much harder to find prior art that has all those specific details. But it also makes it much harder to prove infringement because the competitor has to match every single one of those numerous specific limitations.

So harder to kill, but harder to enforce.

Precisely. It’s this classic trade-off and it leads to that saying What’s sauce for the goose is sauce for the gander. If you, the patent owner, argue that a claim term should be interpreted broadly to catch an infringer, you’re also making it easier for the defendant to argue that the same broad interpretation means the claim reads on some piece of prior art and is therefore invalid. [The patent-specific saying is “That which infringes, if after, invalidates, if before.”]

This tension kind of keeps both sides honest or at least uh strategically constrained. It means patent lawyers aren’t just scribbling words. They’re playing this high stakes game where one adjective could make or break a billion dollar asset.

Given all this back and forth, what about that idea we touched on, companies deliberately not looking at patents, trying to stay ignorant to avoid trouble? That seems odd, given patents are public documents meant to share information.

It does seem odd, and it’s a real strategy, often called the ostrich position. Some tech companies actively discourage their engineers from searching for or reading patents in their field.

Why would they do that?

The thinking is, if you can plausibly claim in court that you had no knowledge of the patent you’re accused of infringing, you might avoid being found liable for willful infringement.

And willful infringement means bigger damages

potentially. Yes, it can lead to the judge multiplying the damages, sometimes up to three times trouble damages. So avoiding knowledge seems like a way to limit financial risk, but as you said, it directly contradicts one of the main purposes of the patent system, which is to disclose technical knowledge publicly to let others learn from it, build on it, and avoid reinventinging the wheel or ignoring prior art because of that Not Invented Here syndrome. Patents are supposed to be a resource, not something you actively avoid. [Cases where a defendant’s “ostrich position” reinforced heightened damages, as demonstrating willful ignorance?]

Right? Okay. Let’s bring this down to earth with that Caltech versus Apple and Broadcom case. A billion dollars for a patent that again maybe looks like just a diagram about error correction codes or something. How does that number even materialize?

Yeah, the Caltech case is a really potent example of the let’s say the sheer texture of patent litigation and how something that seems quite abstract technically can result in these massive damages. First context. Caltech in this scenario acts as a non-practicing entity, an NPE.

Sometimes called a patent troll, though that term is loaded.

It is loaded. Yeah. But basically, it means they license their patents. They don’t make or sell products using the patents themselves. Now, the default way damages are calculated in patent cases is reasonable royalties.

Reasonable royalties. Okay.

The court tries to reconstruct a hypothetical negotiation. What royalty rate would these two parties have agreed upon right before the infringement started assuming both were willing. It’s fictional but guided by up to 15 established factors. The Georgia Pacific factors

15 factors like what things like um are there other existing licenses for this patent? How profitable is the product using the invention? What’s the commercial relationship between the parties? How much of the product’s value is really tied specifically to this patented feature? So that answers the why $1 [billion] question partly. It starts with the the total revenue generated by the infringing products. In this case, you’re talking about huge numbers of Apple iPhones and other devices using Broadcom Wi-Fi chips. Massive revenues.

So, even a small percentage royalty on a huge number is still a huge number.

Exactly. Even a tiny fraction of Apple’s iPhone revenue is enormous. Plus, you have the royalty stacking issue. A complex device like a smartphone might be covered by literally thousands of patents. How do you assign value to just one? In the Caltech case specifically, the patents related to error correction codes used in Wi-Fi standards. Interestingly, it was described as an optional portion of the standard, but one that Apple and Broadcom did choose to implement in their chips. [Broadcom implemented in chips, and Apple chose to adopt Broadcom chips; though in both cases chose to implement an optional part of WiFi standard?]

And getting a jury to understand all that tech must be tough.

Incredibly tough. Juries are usually made up of lay people. They have to grapple with super complex engineering details, standards documents, source code. They rely heavily on testimony from expert witnesses hired by each side and on all the documents turned over during that discovery process we mentioned. It’s a battle of experts and evidence.

It just sounds like the whole process, not just the potential payout, but the fight itself, must be astronomically expensive.

Oh, you’re absolutely right. Patent litigation has been famously called the sport of kings precisely because it’s so incredibly expensive to pursue or defend. Millions, often tens of millions of dollars in legal fees and expert costs.

Wow.

That cost pressure is immense and it often drive settlements even when one side thinks they have a really strong case on the merits. They just can’t afford the fight.

To try and manage this, many federal courts, especially those that hear a lot of patent cases, have adopted special local patent rules, LPRs. [Seems to be suggesting that one reason for courts adopting LPRs was to avoid parties’ strategic use of litigation costs as artificial leverage? Not sure my notes support that.]

LPRs, what do they do?

They try to force the parties to show their cards earlier and with more detail. So, the patent owner has to provide detailed infringement contentions, usually with claim charts, mapping each patent claim limitation to the accused product. And the defendant has to respond early with a detailed invalidity contentions, mapping the claims to prior art. It tries to structure the chaos a bit.

And then impacting the value side, the damages are technical arguments about things like design-arounds.

Meaning, could they have easily avoided infringing?

Exactly. If the defendant can show there were easy, cheap, available alternatives, non-infringing alternatives or NIS that they could have used instead of the patented invention, it suggests the patent wasn’t worth that much. A lower royalty is appropriate. So, the technical ease of designing around the patent heavily influences its monetary value.

Okay, so we’ve really dug into the mechanics here. The courtroom battles, the valuation, the validity challenges, but let’s zoom back out the big picture. The Constitution says patents are supposed to promote the progress of science and useful arts.

Mhm. The grand purpose.

So, does all this this complexity, this cost, these billion dollar lawsuits, does it actually achieve that goal? Does it promote progress?

That right there is the billion dollar question, isn’t it? Or maybe the multi trillion dollar question for the whole economy. Does the system genuinely promote invention or is it maybe more of an incentive to patent? There’s this famous quote from economist Fritz Machlup back in 1958. He studied the patent system extensively and basically concluded if we did not have a patent system, it would be irresponsible on the basis of our present knowledge of its economic consequences to recommend instituting one. But since we have had one for a long time, it would be irresponsible on the basis of our present knowledge to recommend abolishing it.

So basically, don’t really know for sure if it works as intended, but we’re stuck with it. [This sounds superficial, but the audio soon strikes a decent balance.]

That captures the uh the persistent uncertainty pretty well. Decades of economic studies have struggled to definitively prove a strong direct link between the patent system as it exists and the overall rate of innovation across the economy. It’s not just an academic debate either. It means policymakers trying to tweak the system are often flying a bit blind, trying to balance encouraging invention against the risk of creating harmful monopolies or litigation drains. That Caltech case really highlights that tension. You know, a huge payout is that fuel for more innovation or just attacks on existing products.

You could argue the system is somewhat self-referential like a treadmill. Success with patents encourages more patenting which leads to more litigation which shapes how people patent. It creates a lot of activity, a lot of churn. But on the other hand, patents do serve a really important function as handles for technology. They make inventions numbered, classified, defined. They sort of uh reify technology, make it into a tradable asset.

Oh, so that enables licensing.

Exactly. It enables markets for technological knowledge. Licensing like Caltech does is a huge part of it. It even allows for entire business models like fableless semiconductor companies. These companies design sophisticated chips but don’t actually manufacture them. They rely on foundaries. That separation is facilitated by IP rights. So you have this really curious tension baked into every patent. It’s a mix of exclusion and share. The claims are there to exclude others, but the specification, the description part is legally required to share knowledge with the public. Of course, there are potential downsides to the disincentives, that billion dollar Caltech judgment. Ultimately, consumers likely pay for that and higher product prices. It’s like an IP tax. And some argue the system can even create an incentive for tech BS, where patents are used more for marketing hype or attracting investment, like maybe with Theronos or some crude projects, than for representing genuine useful innovation.

It definitely sounds sounds like a system in constant motion, constantly pushing and pulling inventors, companies, the whole economy in different directions. It’s this really complex dance of incentives and yeah, potential roadblocks. [Worth noting that the “constantly pushing and pulling” doesn’t come from patent legislation as such, which changes only infrequently, but from the inventor/PTO interactions with each patent application, and with the case law created by patent litigation.]

It’s absolutely a tight rope walk. You could maybe think of the whole patent process, especially the back and forth with the patent office examiner as society kind of looking over the would-be inventor’s shoulder. The examiner pushes back, citing prior art, questioning the claims, and that process essentially prods the inventor or at least forces them to frame their claims as being more of a departure from what already exists. It forces clarification and ideally pushes towards greater novelty or non-obviousness. But it remains this fundamental puzzle. How can a system built on the right to exclude which can raise prices and block competitors actually end up promoting the diffusion and growth of technology overall?

Yeah, that seems like the core paradox.

I think the simplest answer is that it allows inventors and companies to share some information through of patent disclosure and through licensing without giving away everything. It creates a framework for controlled sharing and market interactions that might not happen otherwise if the only options were complete secrecy or total openness. And we need to remember innovation isn’t just about massive breakthroughs. It’s also about incremental improvements, tweaking existing tech. Patents play a role across that whole spectrum from the garage inventor to the huge R&D labs.

So what does this all mean for you listening in? We’ve taken a deep dive into this surprisingly intricate world of patents, their role in litigation, and their well often debated connection to promoting progress. From those super-detailed claim charts trying to define the precise edge of an invention [in comparison with an accused product or with asserted prior art], all the way to billion-dollar judgments that grab headlines worldwide, it’s clearly a system designed to channel human ingenuity. But wow, not without its complexities, its costs, and its controversies.

Yeah, we’ve seen a patent isn’t just, you know, a certificate saying good idea. It’s a really carefully crafted legal instrument. It defines boundaries, yes, but it also enables licensing. It fuels certain kinds of innovation, even if sometimes the path feels really roundabout or frankly incredibly expensive. It’s a system that provides incentives, definitely, but it also injects huge risks like that possibility [of huge expense?]. We discussed your seemingly rock-solid patent claim turning out to have been precariously perched on treacherous ground when challenged in court.

So, next time you read about a cool new invention or maybe another big tech patent dispute hits the news, maybe Pause and consider this. How much of the progress we see all around us is driven purely by that spark of genius? And how much is it fundamentally shaped, guided, maybe even distorted by this intricate, powerful, and often really contentious legal framework we call the patent system? Thank you for joining us for this deep dive.